Assumption 2. There are so many firms in the industry that each one . . . has no power whatsoever to affect the price of the product
The second first assumption is intended to guarantee that neither individual buyers nor individual sellers can have undue power within any market. This is because, with so many sellers, it would be impossible to operate an effective cartel, since the cost of finding information from so many sources would preclude such an arrangement. Again, because there are so many sellers, none can individually influence the price of the good s/he is selling. Large buyers might also come to have too much power in a market, so the assumption applies also to the demand side of the market.
Is this a realistic view of how modern markets operate? In reality, it flies in the face of the consolidation that has typified capitalism at least since it was critiqued by Marx (what a fantastic beard!). Perhaps in this Information Age we should be most concerned about the heavy consolidation in the world of media, as demonstrated by the merger of AOL and Time-Warner, two of the largest global media corporations, in 2001. Since the merger the group has gone from strength to strength, now out-competing other providers of high-speed internet connections and seeing profits increase by 76% in the last quarter of 2004.
Let us carry out that manoeuvre so detested by economists and test out this assumption against the reality of the market for food in the UK at the beginning of the 21st century. The reality is that the market is dominated by a small number of very powerful players—the supermarkets. As middlemen, standing between producers and consumers, they both buy and sell food, and ensure that what economic theory might consider the ‘buyers’ and ‘sellers’ have to meet their in needs in terms not only of price, but also in terms of quality. According to Corporate Watch research, in 2000 the major supermarket chains controlled 88 per cent of the UK food market, a concentration of retail power far greater than in continental EU countries or the USA. Later that year analysts predicted that the number of major players would be down from the existing five—Tesco, Sainsburys, Safeway, Asda, and Somerfield—to just two.
So much for competition: without a large number of potential entrants to the market, what mechanism does the market offer to constrain their behaviour? This assumption relies on a separate sub-theory focused around the concept of ‘barriers to entry’. In order to ensure that there are plenty of buyers and sellers in the market, there must be nothing to stop the potential market players from entering the market, no ‘barriers’. Competition only works when there are large numbers of suppliers who cannot unduly influence our purchasing decisions or preventing other producers from entering the market and improving on their offer to us as consumers.
This view may have made sense why you consider the 18th-century market that Adam Smith visited, where he might have bought meat, potatoes and shoes, but it has little relevance in a complex, modern economy where purchasing decisions are based on advertising and goods do not reach the market without many years of development and massive R&D investment. Or to a market where a new item cannot reach the consumer's attention without massive investment in branding and advertising.
Parkin and King deal with advertising as follows: ‘To the extent that advertising provides consumers with information about the precise nature of the differentiation of products, it serves a valuable purpose, enabling consumers to make a better product choice’. Sloman deals with advertising as follows: ‘There is no point in advertising under perfect competition, since all firms produce a homogeneous product (unless, of course, the firm believes that by advertising it can differentiate its product from its rivals’ and thereby establish some market power; but then, by definition, the firm would cease to be perfectly competition’ (p. 156). Trying to imagine what kind of advertising might conform to this the world of the perfectly competitive theory Mr. Cholmondley-Warner sprung into my head, kindly pointing out in his received pronunciation that Mr. McVitie is now producing his digestive biscuits with chocolate on top. If this was all advertising were about why would companies spend millions on it every year? Why would there by whole journals dedicated to informing company executives of the most effective ways to manipulate the minds of potential buyers?
In reality, the business of a corporation in the global economy focuses on holding its market share and defending it against all-comers. The business of corporate capitalism is not about perfect competition but about obstructing competition. This is done not only through creating and defending the corporation’s unique identity through its brand, but also through investing in advertising and PR to support its brand and litigation to attack those who transgress it, and through concealing virtually everything about its operations, from the details of how its products are made (remember the Coca Cola secret recipe?) to how it spends its profits.
Tweet
Hi Molly,
ReplyDeleteEnjoying your writing. It's useful for non-economists like me to have some basic ideas explained from a green perspective. It seems there's a huge vacuum in economics at present just waiting for new minds like yourself to fill. This may be the era that economics finds it's place in a living world. p.s. have you read this book ? You would enjoy.
http://www.geoffdavies.com/economia.html
Haven't read it. Just rushing so badly. Check out today's blog and space and time and tell me how I can keep getting this so wrong??!!
ReplyDelete